After cyber puppet, Chandra Babu, the ‘Swadeshi’
Indian government has presented to its people yet another imperialist recruit
the once Gandhian-turned Swadeshi, P.R. Kumaramangalam. With him dead another
puppet will replace him. Popularly known as ‘Ranga’, Kumaramangalam was an
active trade union leader, shared the leftist leanings of his family, and came
out forcefully and publicly against the economic reforms of the imperialists,
stamping them as being responsible for the ‘distortion and corruption’ in
Indian politics. The denouncement of this ‘ranga’ (drama) was his resignation as
Parliamentary Affairs Minister of the Narasimha Rao’s government in 1993, to
become a staunch ‘swadeshi’ by joining the BJP.
Being guided by his new masters, Kumaramangalam
relenting his antagonist stand against economic reforms, now advocated the need
of no less than Rs. 2 lakh crores for the additional generation of 50,000MW of
power during the Ninth Plan Period, to be met through private sector investment.
And since the private sector was not coming forward with investment as it was
wary of the regulations in vogue, especially the tariff structure, the swadeshi-branded
Power Minister pleaded that ‘Unless existing regulations are changed and the
tariff structure is made more viable and enforceable, the much needed fillip to
the power sector may not come through. My priority therefore is to bring the
policy changes through legislation in the matter of tariffs by bringing into
existence a tariff commission’ (Powerline, Apr. ’98).
So with the aim of promoting "the much needed
fillip to the power sector by the private investors", Ranga unprecedentedly
engaged an economic research institute. (the National Council of Applied
Economic Research) to undertake preparations for the proposed Electricity Bill,
2000. Philosophized and engineered by the client’s brief, the research institute
fulfilled their contractual obligation and presented the draft bill for the
proposed legislation to the Ministry of Power
"intended to accelerate the reforms necessary to ensure a healthy power industry
in India."
The sole strategy of the reform, sought to be
legitimised by this Bill, aims at dismemberment of the Electricity Boards under
the state sector, winding them up and making distress sales to private
operators. The power sector is intended to be made free for all, answerable to
none, and the role of the State reduced to that of a helpless spectator.
This may be an easy way out for the government
but it leaves a host of serious questions unanswered. The salient features of
the Bill, are summarised below :
(1) The restructuring and modernisation of this
industry is now inevitable if the goal of providing universal access to reliable
and affordable electricity is to be achieved in the foreseeable future.
(2) States may keep SEBs or may privatise them. In
any case, SEBs will have to act as a business organisation.
(3) Transmission Companies under the Companies Act,
1956 in vogue, will be reconstituted through public and private investment for
evacuation and transmission of power from different Generating Companies.
(4) Transmission companies will enter into
agreement with Area
Distributor/Distributor/Subsidiary/Associate/Purchaser/Retailer for transmission
and distribution of power. The latter may also enter into sub-contract with any
individual or group of individuals for distribution of power to the end
consumers.
(5) An Electricity Regulatory Commission
(Centre/State) will take policy decisions regarding fixing of tariff/fuel
surcharge/cess, taking the reasonable profit element, at every level, into
consideration.
(6) Before dismemberment of the SEBs, the
respective States will constitute ‘Corporations’ (Generation /Transmission/
Distribution) registered under the Companies Act, 1956. TRANSCO will come up as
the main company.
(7) After the unbundling of the SEBs, all their
assets will vest with the State Government., and the state government in turn
will hand over the assets to the respective stake holders in accordance with the
sale deeds. The liabilities of the erstwhile SEBs including the terminal
benefits of their employees will be met from the sale value of the assets thus
received by the government.
(8) The respective state governments will transfer
the employees of the erstwhile SEBs, under the different companies, as per terms
mentioned in the transfer scheme. Steps will however be taken to see that the
posts held and the pay enjoyed by the employees may not be less favourable.
After transfer to the new employer, employment will be regulated by the
Regulations of the stake holders.
However, employees are not entitled to prefer any suit against the
Government/Stake Holder/SEB for any relief or compensation for such transfer in
any court.
(9) The consumers will have to enter into fresh
agreement, with the distributor of power, at their own cost.
(10) One of the functions and duties of the
Electricity Regulatory Commission (Centre/State) is to promote, encourage and
assist private investment in the electricity industry. Disputes arising out of
the decision of the Regulatory Commission can only be raised in the Division
Bench of the High Courts.
(11) The government (Centre/state) will arrange the
acquisition of land for the private investors in such a manner as if the land
will be required to meet the exigencies of the government.
(12) The government will arrange subvention
(subsidy) to the investors, from the exchequer, either as aid and/or loan and
also act as guarantor for any market loan and interest there of, taken by the
investors.
(13) The new power projects are eligible for a
five-year tax holiday.
(14) Duties on the import of equipment for the
power project had been reduced considerably initially and currently they are
zero.
The proposed legislation would, it appears, satisfy
only one interest, that of the profit-seeking investor. That seems to be the
only purpose served by the Electricity Bill, 2000.
Be it mentioned in this connection that
Notifications have been amended from time to time, in tune with the demands of
the foreign investors. For example, in the matter of Capital cost for power
plants, the principal notification was issued in March, 1992, amended twice in
1994, twice in 1995 and four times in the first half of 1997.
Prior to the present legislation, the Electricity
(Supply) Act, 1948 was amended in 1991 to facilitate the setting up of private
generating stations. In 1998, the Electricity Act, 1910 was amended for enabling
private investment in the transmission sector. In the same year, the Electricity
Regulatory Commissions Act, 1998 was enacted to provide for Regulatory
Commissions at the Centre and in the States for tariff-setting and regulation of
the electricity industry. So far six States, namely Orissa, Haryana, Andhra
Pradesh, Karnataka, Rajasthan and Uttar Pradesh have enacted their respective
laws to provide for the setting up of separate corporate entities for the
generation, transmission and distribution of electricity in place of the
existing SEBs. Some other States are actively considering similar measures.
Consequences of Reforms Carried out
So Far
The National Working Group on Power, headed by N.S.
Vasant, former Chairman, Punjab State Electricity Board, reviewed the whole
situation. The Working Group has stated that "it is distressing that the
reforms are being carried out in spite of negative results verging on disaster".
Their study report has collated the following results :
(i) The Maharashtra State Electricity Board (MSEB),
so far a profit making Board, is now expected to end up making a loss of over Rs.
1,700 crores in the year 1999-2000. In Maharashtra, Enron’s Dabhol Power
Corporation (DPC) tariff is Rs. 4.76 per unit (Fuel cost ranges between Rs. 2 to
2.25 per unit and capacity charges are about Rs. 1.60) as against an average
generation cost of Rs. 0.32 per unit from MSEB’s hydro-electric stations, Rs.
1.25 from the thermal stations and around Rs. 1.40 from the NTPC. The MSEB is
forced to close down its own generation, and purchase costlier power; it cannot
reduce the PLF of the DPC since the LNG (liquid natural gas) contract has
already been made for 22% PLF. With the completion of DPC (Phase I & II) not
only would MSEB, but even the state of Maharashtra would become bankrupt since
the DPC is covered by guarantees and counter guarantees. At this rate, MSEB and
the Government of Maharashtra, in due course, may be forced to start selling its
assets/power houses to Enron (as happened in Uttar Pradesh and Orissa against
the arrears of NTPC).
(ii) In Orissa the losses of GENCO (the generation
part of the erstwhile SEB) were Rs. 294.99 crores in 1996-97 against Rs. 230.65
incurred by the parent OSEB in 1995-96. Supply to the rural areas has been
stopped. AES (an American investor in GENCO) has come up with the claim of
enhancing tariffs three times, or else the AES should be compensated to the tune
of Rs. 300 crores for damages during the cyclone, since the company was in the
process of arranging an insurance cover when the super cyclone hit Orissa.
After four years of reform in the power sector in
Orissa under the gaze of the World Bank, the Bank’s Country Director, Edwin Lim
wrote to Orissa’s Chief Secretary to rescue GRIDCO (the transmission company)
from the debt-servicing burden, and sought assistance from the Government of
India. The centre promptly complied with a financial restructuring package of Rs.
2,715 crores, lest the set-back should send negative signals to other reforming
states such as Andhra Pradesh, Haryana, Karnataka and Uttar Pradesh.
Preparatory to privatisation of the four
distribution zones of Orissa, their accounts were separated from those of GRIDCO
and four companies were incorporated. The four distribution companies together
had liabilities of over Rs. 2,000 crores. But the Bank suggested that GRIDCO
transfer only part of these liabilities and take on itself the rest. This was in
order to make the distribution companies attractive to prospective buyers. In
1999, 51 per cent of the shares of the Distribution companies (DISTCOs) were
sold to the highest bidder. The Regulatory Commission allowed retail tariffs to
be fixed in a way that would cover the cost of bulk power purchases by the
DISTCOs from the GRIDCO, plus a 16 per cent return on the investments made in
the purchase of the companies, with an allowance for transmission and
distribution losses (ranging to 50 per cent, against an internationally accepted
norm of 7 per cent).
(iii) The Haryana State Electricity Board has since
been unbundled and corporatised, firstly by separating generation and
transmission. Later, transmission has been divided into four distribution
companies and a transmission company. International agencies, other than the
World Bank, have chipped in with $400 million. They included OECF (Japan), KfW
(Germany) and DFID (UK). Technical assistance are being provided as a grant, and
not a loan, by the international agencies like DFID, USEA, USAID and CIDA. DFID
will focus on regulatory commission, corporatisation, financial restructuring,
distribution, privatisation and a broad-based execution of the ‘reform’. It will
also provide a communication strategy and personal management. CIDA will help
provide expansion and planning.
(iv) The Government of Madhya Pradesh is learnt to
have accepted the recommendation of the Tata Rao Committee towards restructuring
of the Madhya Pradesh State Electricity Board. Multinational companies like
Daewoo Power, Power Gen, GBL Power, Pench Power, STI, Guna and Shree Maheshwar
Hydel are some of the agencies operating on the generation side, in the state. A
consortium of the KEC International and Crompton Greaves has been awarded with
the charge of the transmission system. A new 600 KM long 400 KV double circuit
line would be developed by this consortium on a build-own-transfer basis.
(v) The generation part of the state-owned power
sector in Tripura has been handed over to a private investor NEEPCO.
(vi) The Kerala Government has since drawn up a
package of reforms.
The transmission and distribution losses, which was
a major plank of the reforms, have gone soaring in the ‘reformed’ states : This
will be evident from the following table :
State
|
Transmission
&
Distribution
Loss
(per
centum)
|
Pre-reform
|
Post-reform
|
Orissa
|
23
|
51
|
Andhra
Pradesh
|
25
|
45
|
Haryana
|
32
|
40
|
Rajasthan
|
26
|
43
|
(Source
:
Ministry
of
Power,
Government
of
India
–
Presentation
on
Power
Sector
Reforms)
|
The draft of the Bill was presented to the
conference of the Chief Ministers and Power Ministers on 26th February, 2000.
The problems identified by the conference were :
(i) outstanding dues of the SEBs
(ii) inability of the governments (Centre/State) to provide budgetary support,
due to fiscal deficits
(iii) unsustainability of cross-subsidies by the industry
Primary factors
identified for these ills were :
(i) theft of electricity
(ii) technical losses in transmission and distribution, and
(iii) poor operational efficiency of 50% of the thermal plants in the State
sector
To any rational person, it would be obvious that
the solution to none of these problems lie in drastic legislative and structural
changes of the industry. The root cause of the poor financial health of SEBs is
not on account of extant laws, but due to its violation by the governments. The
problems of outstanding dues and partially even the poor operational performance
is a consequence of the massive corruption and willful violation by the state
governments of Sec.59 of the Electricity (Supply) Act, 1948 which statutorily
require the state governments to assure SEBs a minimum rate of return of 3% on
their invested capital.
As far as theft is concerned, the problem is not
inadequate legislation to deal with criminals, but the lack of will to enforce
the law. Much of the theft is by big industry and rural elite linked to the
politicians.
The basic objectives
of the proposed legislation are therefore :
(i) to enforce the unbundling of the vertically
integrated SEBs in order to facilitate the privatisation of the generation,
transmission and distribution components and also to facilitate the
multinationals to replace a public sector monopoly with a private monopoly (e.g.
AES Orissa). It is ironical that vertically integrated private power sector
companies like CESC, Tata Electric Company etc., have been kept undisturbed.
(ii) to create institutions that have no
accountability to the legislature, yet regulate to guarantee big profits on a
highly capital intensive industry (wherein a single paisa increase in tariffs
implies an additional annual revenue of Rs. 70,000 per MW at 80% PLF).
(iii) to create a ‘half slave and half free’ sector
wherein the Regulators (State/Centre) would control the tariffs of the public
funded institutions, but the tariffs for the private sector (particularly the
foreign funded sector) would be dictated by power purchase agreements and would
be outside the purview of the Regulators.
(iv) to ensure that the state is demobilised and
the entire fund requirement in this core sector industry, is based on, and
controlled by, international finance capital.
(v) to maximise private profit by ensuring the
elimination of ceiling on profits.
(vi) to provide this essential public service only
to those who can pay, thereby threatening the power supply to rural areas and
the farm sector and the urban poor.
(vii) to enable multinational corporations to take
over, on their own terms, the assets of the SEBs.
Can Bengal Lag Behind
?
As far as ‘reforms’ in the power sector is
concerned, West Bengal under the governance of the Left Front government is the
pioneer, far to speak to speak of lagging behind. It may be recalled that
when the objective of privatising the power sector to make room for the
imperialists was in its embryonic form, the West Bengal government mutilated two
supply stations of the WBSEB and formed the Singur-Haripal Rural Electricity
Co-operative Ltd., in the year 1980. In 1987 the government floated a
company in the name of the "Power Development Corporation Ltd." and handed over
Kolaghat Thermal Power Project, a 210X6MW project under construction by WBSEB,
to it. Further dismemberment of the WBSEB was done by the Lavpur RE Cooperative
Societies Ltd., in the district of Birbhoom, and by the Sagardwip Rural Energy
Development Cooperative Society Ltd. in 24-Parganas (South). In 1999 yet another
company was constituted by the government in the name of the West Bengal Rural
Energy Development Corporation Ltd., essentially a power distribution company,
whose objective, in the long term, is to supply ‘power on demand’ in the rural
areas. In the meantime, the WBSEB, vide its circular, intimated to all concerned
that the government had decided to bring the thermal power stations under the
WBPDCL in phases, to function as separate business units. Be it mentioned that
both WBPDCL and WBREDCL are registered under the Companies Act, 1956 having
their own Memorandum of Associations and Memorandum of Articles. The REDCL will
purchase power at rates and terms set by the Power Purchase Agreement (PPA).
While the management of these two companies are corporatised, the works of
distribution of power, line maintenance, new connections, fuse calls, meter
reading and billing, collection etc., will be done contractually. The government
preaches that such steps in the power sector is not privatisation, but is an
attempt at restructuring, since the SEB is not able to cope with the burden of
responsibility as it stands at present. Over and above this, the SEB is reeling
under a debt trap, and has reduced itself to insolvency and hence no financial
institution is coming up to help with a rescue package by giving loans etc. In
its propaganda, the government is audacious enough to suppress the following
salient points :
(i) Despite constraints imposed by the government
and interference from the political level, the SEB did extremely well upto the
major part of the seventies. But the government has seldom permitted the
autonomy provided for SEB in the statutes. The SEB is compelled to shoulder the
blame of mis-management, inefficiency and deterioration in the quality of
service.
(ii) The WBSEB has been reduced to the status of
mere trader in place of producer. It is compelled to meet the power demand of
the State through purchases from outside agencies, the quantum of which is more
than double its own generation.
(iii) There is a direction from the State
government to the WBSEB for guaranteed off-take at the rate of 80% PLF from
other outside agencies. As a result the WBSEB has to hike up or tone down its
own generation, resulting in seriously effecting its own per capital production
cost.
(iv) Both the Central and State governments have
large unpaid bills, kept as arrears due to the WBSEB for their consumption of
power. This is more than 30% of SEB’s total revenue.
(v) No financial help or subsidy is borne by the
government for the supply of power and maintenance of the system with regard to
the Kutir Jyoti and Lokdeep projects.
(vi) Theft of energy, which ranges from 7-8%, tells
upon the financial health of the WBSEB. Such theft takes place under the
political patronage of the party in power. It may be recalled that a 1% loss of
energy means 450 MW loss of power.
(vii) The state government is totally indifferent
to the WBSEB taking action for realising energy bills from some big companies.
This amount ranges upto Rs. 1,000 crores.
Some lessons and
tasks confronting the workers/employees working in the Public Sector power
industries
The Electricity Bill 2000 is being brought into
being superseding a host of acts passed earlier, such as the Electricity Act
1910, and the Electric Supply Act (1948). The net result of the proposed Act
consists in the unbundling of the huge public sector power enterprises, i.e.,
State Electricity Boards (SEBs).
The aim of Electricity Bill 2000 is supposedly to
"provide universal access to reliable and affordable electricity." In the
preface to the Bill, it was recognised that immediately after the transfer of
power, "nationalisation was considered essential at that time for extending
power utility to the vast rural and economically backward regions across the
country." But it has, in the same breath, been pointed out that the SEBs now
"began to face serious difficulties over the years owing to their inability
to recover costs and ineffeciencies arising out of their unwieldy structure."
Hence an all-India meet of Chief Ministers of various states, in the year 1996,
recognised the widening gap between demand and supply, and identified the need
for corporatisation and restructuring of the SEBs (i.e., privatisation), and
even abolishing the Boards altogether, and decided enactment of laws towards
this end by their respective legislatures. Accordingly, some six states have
enacted their respective laws to provide for the splitting of the Boards and
creation of separate entities for generation, transmission and distribution of
power. West Bengal’s Left Front Government has also made up its mind to
privatise and corporatise the power industry step by step and not in a hurry
partly due to employees’s pressure, and partly due to the fact that the West
Bengal Government has already taken steps in that direction through the creation
of the power development corporations. This was long before the BJP even thought
of it.
Now about avowed aims regarding the universal
access to reliable and affordable electricity. The aforesaid social aims would
have to be drastically curtailed as each of the three components—production,
transmission and distribution — would be run separately and according to market
and commercial policies of profits and business viability. It may further be
noted that after passing through at least three power purchasing agreements (PPA)
ensuring a lucrative amount of guaranteed returns (profits), the consumers will
ultimately receive electricity at enormously inflated prices. So it may be safe
to conclude that the common people, particularly the rural folk, getting power,
to light up the dark recesses of their huts, would remain a pipe dream. Further,
it is assumed that privatisation and the opening up of the power industries to
the big comprador capitalists and imperialist TNCs would throw up a ‘level
playing field’ for competition which would supposedly bring down costs. But the
reality is that with the massive capital involved, and the hi-tech schemes
envisaged, it is the multinationals that will dominate this sector.
So, what would result, is a switch from state
monopoly to the monopoly of the TNCs.
An example of sorts is the meter-reading and
billing of the thousands of consumers in the urban as well as rural areas
through private cooperatives and panchayats respectively. These two bodies, in
their turn, would be forced, out of business principles, to hand over such
operations to the enterprises with ‘expertise’ to complete the tasks quicker
than indigenous agencies.
So, as a result of this privatisation of electric
power, the cost to the consumer will go up three to five fold and lakhs of
employees will lose their jobs. While the bulk of the profits will get siphoned
off abroad by the TNCs. In all ways it will be an outright disaster for the
country.
The foregoing plans of the governments, demands a
dogged struggle by the power workers unitedly, not only for their immediate
demands, but against privatisation, and to reorganise the existing public
utilities to ensure both viability and the fulfillment of social aims. From the
nature of restructuring of the power industries in the matrix of capitalist
globalisation, it is obvious that a major section of the workforce, including
the better-paid engineers, are arrayed against this privatisation, simply for
their existence. The earlier struggle of the UP power workers showed this. Add
also to this, the strength, of a sizable section belonging to the contract,
casual and daily-rated workers, whose numbers are swelling day by day. In the
power sector itself, if united, there is a mighty force arrayed against the
perpetrators of these evil policies.
But, the struggle cannot be confined only to the
employees of the power sector. Every single consumer of electricity in this
country will be badly hit. The worst to be hit will be the rural masses and the
urban poor and middle classes.
A militant struggle by all these forces can
definitely stall the process of privatisation of power. And a more determined
struggle, to kick the imperialists out of our country, and smash their lackeys
within, is the only guarantee for reversing the process of privatisation in
total.
|