On the Political Economy of Mexico Agrarian Revolution and Semi-Feudalism
This article
is excerpted from the pamphlet of the same name by Isidro Serrano
which originally appeared in 1991 in Mexico. AWTW
INTRODUCTION
In ordinary times, the countryside and the peasants are hidden,
almost forgotten by Mexican society. The official society is that
of the city, an urban one, and even more so that of the capital,
Mexico City. The peasants search for a refuge from the hunger
that threatens the countryside, they move in the shadows of the
city dwellers as squatters, street vendors, beggars, proletarians
with minuscule salaries. They come out of the shadows for an instant
to be given the anonymous fame of being "the illegal immigrant
problem of the United States". The government, preoccupied by
"social peace", constantly promises them "justice". But in the
countryside they are almost invisible.
They burst out every now and again in the city in one protest
or another. Sometimes vague, brief journalist's notes mention
the massacre of another half dozen peasants the murder of just
one is almost not considered to be "news". The rest of the time
they pay attention to the peasants only as it concerns how to
extract more production, more exports and more foreign exchange.
With all of this, in the crucial moments in the life of the country,
from this almost invisible world, from this vast oblivion, from
these "humble" peasants, have risen up ardent and ferocious legions
have arisen from among the peasants that have ignited the entire
country with the flames of revolution, while official society
staggered with shock and fear. They tell us that this is all a
thing of the past; Mexico is no longer an agricultural country;
much of the land has already been divided up; now everything is
capitalist (or a "mixed economy"); now the peasants are only a
sector that can either provide the [ruling] PRI with captive audiences
or the opposition with votes.
Those who think this are mistaken. There are innumerable signs
that indicate that the country is approaching a decisive moment
once again. The downtrodden will arise again from the shadows
and in their ranks the bitter cry from the countryside will be
heard once more. If the revolutionaries know how to act correctly,
that cry will herald a new revolutionary storm, and the peasants,
in firm unity with their proletarian brothers in the city, will
finally find their own voice in the melody of people's war.
I.
THE PEASANT ROAD AND THE LANDLORD ROAD
The oppression of the peasants in Mexico has its historic roots
in the feudal and colonial society which Spain imposed on us.
There exist two roads to overcome feudalism in the countryside:
the landlord road and the peasant road. The landlord road is the
conservative road of slow transformation of the feudal landlords
into capitalists. The peasant road is the revolutionary road of
overcoming feudalism through confiscating the land belonging to
the landlords without compensation and dividing it among the peasants.1
In spite of the so-called agrarian reform, the road followed by
Mexico has essentially been the landlord road, the road of the
gradual transformation of the feudal landlords into capitalists.
The reform helped to accelerate the transformation of the feudal
landlords into agricultural capitalists by taking away their marginal
lands. On a few occasions peasants were given good lands to hold
back and stop their revolutionary struggle. But there is no doubt
that the transformation of the feudal landlords into bourgeoisie
has been the main road to the expansion of capitalist relations
in the countryside. The peasant economy, on the other hand, has
been hemmed in, restricted and subordinated at each step.
The landlord road is the conservative and counter-revolutionary
road. It fully corresponds to the maintenance of the semi-colonial
character of the country and its domination by imperialism, mainly
US imperialism. The big bourgeoisie which has arisen in the countryside
from this road is a bureaucrat-comprador bourgeoisie, dependent
and subordinate to imperialism. Capitalism generated by imperialist
capital and its Mexican minor partner is bureaucrat capitalism
in the sense given to this term by Mao: capitalism that is completely
subordinated to imperialism and closely linked to semi-feudal
relations, both in the state-owned and the private forms of capital.
This bureaucrat capitalism is the "state-owned monopoly, comprador
and feudal capitalism" that arises in the colonial or semi-colonial
and semi-feudal countries under imperialist domination.2
Even though the landlord road and the expansion of imperialist
and bureaucrat-comprador capital in a semi-colonial country like
ours tends, in the long run, toward the elimination of feudal
relations, in the medium term this transforms them only partly,
adapts them to the needs of big capital and reproduces them partially.
That is the reason why semi-feudalism persists in the Mexican
countryside and, as we will see, still plays an important role
in the operation of the system as a whole. Even where feudal relations
are transformed into capitalist relations, transformation through
the landlord road is always counter-revolutionary in the political
sense, that is to say, it always reproduces the subordination
and oppression of the rural workers, albeit in a more capitalist
form.
Which road today opposes the landlord road? The rise of the struggle
in the 1970s proved without doubt that the main opposition in
the countryside is the peasant struggle, mainly the struggle for
land.3 It proved that, in spite of the considerable expansion
of capitalist relations through the landlord road in the postwar
period, the peasant road continues to be the immediate alternative
bursting forth from the concrete reality of the class struggle
in the countryside.
The peasant road, in its most radical expression, is the revolutionary
road that destroys feudalism, not through the gradual transformation
of feudal landlords into bourgeoisie, but through the complete
expropriation of the landlord class, the distribution of all the
land among the peasants and the consequent elimination of the
oppression and exploitation of the peasants by the landlords.
Today, with significant bourgeoisification of the landlords and
the ever greater presence of imperialist capital in the agro-industrial
complex, the peasant struggle has not only a deep anti-feudal
content but it also directly confronts big imperialist and bureaucrat-comprador
capital. This creates an even firmer objective basis to forge
the worker-peasant alliance under proletarian leadership.
In fact, the main conflict in the countryside is between the continuation
of the landlord road under the command of big capital subordinated
to imperialism and tied to semi-feudalism, and the peasant road
which is most sharply expressed in the struggle to wipe out the
domination of imperialism, bureaucrat capitalism and semi-feudalism
in the countryside and replace it with a peasant economy. Whoever
opposes or downplays this peasant struggle, whoever underestimates
the revolutionary potential of the peasants, is not a true revolutionary,
and in the final analysis not even a consistent democrat. Such
is the case of the "workerists" who, after a lot of hemming and
hawing, conclude that the hundreds of thousands of peasants who
have risen in struggle for land in the last decades were mistaken
and should abandon "the populist fiction according to which it
is necessary to promote the distribution of land to strengthen
the small peasant economy".4 The peasants, they say, did not concern
themselves with the truly "proletarian" struggle...the struggle
for trade unions for jornaleros [day labourers their payment is
on a daily, not hourly, basis]! Incredibly, they even say this
without blushing.
Of course there is nothing wrong in itself that jornaleros try
to organize a union. What is extremely wrong and revisionist is
that so-called "Marxists" tell the peasants that the most important
and "proletarian" struggle is the struggle for jornalero unions.
For the revolutionary proletariat, the trade union struggle is
not even the most important or "proletarian" struggle for urban
proletarians that point of view, Lenin teaches us, is economism
and serves the political interests of the bourgeoisie. All the
worse to propose it to the peasants, where it can only serve as
a cover for contempt and even opposition to the main current which
the struggle has adopted, especially among the poor peasants (and
jornaleros), in the periods of their most radical surges: the
struggle for land. The method, the attitude toward the peasantry
and the political point of view which are manifested here have
much in common with those of a previous "workerist" tendency:
the Mensheviks during the Russian Revolution.5
Likewise, the struggle for land, as any other struggle, can lend
itself to purely reformist purposes and the Secretariat of Agrarian
Reform exists to ensure it does. After all, history shows that
obtaining land without armed struggle for political power only
reproduces the subordination of the masses to the reactionary
system. The task of the revolutionary communists is not to passively
support the spontaneous peasant struggle, but to encourage the
tendency toward the highest form of class struggle: people's war.
In this essay we do not consider the very important questions
of military strategy, but it is not possible to correctly focus
on the agrarian question or any other question of revolution without
taking into account the simple conclusion of historical materialism
that true revolutionary transformation occurs only through the
road of armed struggle. Revolutionary victory is unthinkable without
the uprising of the oppressed in the countryside in a country
like ours where more or less half of the people can be found in
towns with less than 15,000 inhabitants6 and this does not include
millions from the countryside who are temporary immigrants in
the USA or migrant workers in the cities of Mexico.
The revolutionary participation of the peasants in the history
of the country has always expressed itself through armed forms,
and this revolutionary force has not yet been exhausted. There
is in fact a war in the countryside: according to the fragmentary
reports available, a peasant is murdered every three days in the
course of struggling for land or against the political bosses
(caciques) or in other peasant struggles.7 The problem is that
this war is very unequal, in spite of the occasional outbreaks
of spontaneous armed resistance by the peasants. For the revolutionary
peasants the final solution has always been and continues to be
replying to reactionary violence with revolutionary violence of
the masses.
For all these reasons, in spite of the big differences between
contemporary Mexico and China before liberation, the challenge
which Mao posed continues to be a dividing line for us: the peasants
"will rise like a mighty storm, like a hurricane, a force so swift
and violent that no power, however great, will be able to hold
them back. They will smash all the trammels that bind them and
rush forward along the road to liberation..... Every revolutionary
party and every revolutionary comrade will be put to the test,
to be accepted or rejected as they decide. There are three alternatives.
To march at their head and lead them? To trail behind them, gesticulating
and criticizing, or to stand in their way and oppose them? Every(one)
is free to choose, but events will force you to make the choice
quickly."8
II.
THE PEASANT ROAD AND THE SOCIALIST ROAD
We have said that whoever in fact opposes the peasant struggle
is not a revolutionary, and not even a consistent democrat. Considering
the question from another perspective, in the agrarian revolution
the class-conscious proletariat must consider as allies not only
the (true) socialists but also every democrat who supports the
struggle above all the revolutionary struggle of the peasants.
The immediate struggle is not a directly socialist struggle, rather
it is a struggle between the landlord road and the peasant road.
This peasant road in its most consistent expression leads to an
agrarian revolution that divides all the land among the peasants,
confiscates imperialist and bureaucrat-comprador capital and makes
possible the free development of the peasant economy. It is a
democratic revolution.
The democratic forces, even the "campesinistas" [those who exaggerate
the qualities of the peasants, thinking they alone will carry
out revolution AWTW], who do not see beyond the "free development"
of the peasant economy and promote various ideas and theories,
can be political allies to the extent that they support and promote
this agrarian revolution and the national revolution of which
it is part. Where revolutionary communists distinguish themselves
from their democratic allies in the agrarian revolution is in
understanding that leaving the "free development of the peasant
economy" to its spontaneous course, according to the laws of the
market, is in the end also capitalist development: a more open
and democratic development than that brought about by the landlord
road, but capitalist development nonetheless.
This does not prevent the communists from putting themselves in
the vanguard of the agrarian revolution, because it is the most
revolutionary transformation possible in the present conditions
and because that revolution opens the road not only to a possible
capitalist development but also to the possibility of the broader
and more deep-going participation of the peasants in a subsequent
socialist transformation of the countryside and the whole society.
In order to bring about this latter possibility, the communists
must not get carried away by the populist tales of the inherently
"anti-capitalist" or "socialist" nature of the peasant struggle,
or of how "harmful" the leadership of the proletariat and its
Marxist-Leninist-Maoist party is, and the like.
We must say to the peasants openly: the first stage of the agrarian
revolution will mean a great blow to the ruling system and all
must unite and struggle for it. However, once they have the land
and the means to make it produce, two roads will open up to the
peasants: 1) development according to the laws of the market,
which inevitably leads to class polarization within the peasantry
and the exploitation of the immense majority by the new bourgeoisie
which could only ally itself with imperialism and restore semi-colonial
oppression on the country; or, 2) the socialist road which passes
through the voluntary collectivization of the countryside as an
integral part of the socialist transformation of the entire society.
Socialist collectivization represents a second great revolution
in the countryside, which confronts real enemies who want to take
the capitalist road. Socialist collectivization is the only salvation
for the great majority of the peasants, the only way to avoid
being subjected once again to exploitation. Therefore "the poor
and lower-middle peasants... enthusiastically want to continue
the socialist road".9 The final goal of the proletariat revolution
is not the utopian and impossible attempt of indefinitely prolonging
the peasant economy, but the definitive liberation of humanity:
communism, classless society, throughout the world.
To prepare the transition to socialist revolution both in the
agrarian revolution and in the national-democratic revolution,
the leadership of the revolutionary proletariat and its Marxist-Leninist-Maoist
Party is indispensable. There is no need for another democratic
revolution of the old type, that is, led by the bourgeoisie, like
the revolution of 1910 which in the final analysis was incapable
of resolving the great problems which still afflict the country.
What is necessary is a new-democratic revolution led by the proletariat
and its party which smashes imperialism, bureaucrat capitalism
and semi-feudalism, establishes the people's democratic dictatorship
and begins the socialist revolution.
To sum up, the policy of the revolutionary communists in the agrarian
revolution is guided by two fundamental principles. First, the
agrarian revolution in its present stage corresponds necessarily
to the peasant road, the peasants represent the principal revolutionary
force and the communists must lead their struggle above all their
armed struggle against imperialism, bureaucrat capitalism and
semi-feudalism. Second, this first stage of the agrarian revolution
can pave the way either to a new capitalist development, even
if it is under the signboard of the free development of the peasant
economy, or else to socialist transformation, and the latter is
always the strategic perspective of the revolutionary proletariat
and its most important ally, the poor peasants.
III.
FEUDALISM AND THE COLONY
Both the landlord road and the peasant road are ways of overcoming
feudalism in the country. But, what is feudalism?
The essence of feudalism lies in the latifundia system and serfdom,
that is feudal ownership of land and the corresponding relations
of production and exploitation. Under feudalism, control of the
land is the key to exploitation: appropriation by the exploiting
class (the landlords) of the surplus produced by the exploited
(the peasants). By contrast, under capitalism land is only one
among many forces of production and it is the control of capital,
not only of land, that makes exploitation possible.
The feudal landlord class often gives the peasants parcels of
land on which they can produce their sustenance as a condition
of their exploitation by the landlords, whether in the form of
land rent, peonage or others. Since in this way the peasants actually
possess some land and its products, exploitation always implies
the existence of what Marx calls "extra-economic coercion": open
or disguised coercion to obtain the surplus, in other words, servitude
in its broadest sense.
Thus under feudalism the direct producer (the peasant) is linked
to the land; capitalism, instead, presupposes the complete separation
of the direct producer (the wage worker) from the land or any
other means of subsistence. Under feudalism the peasant produces
their own sustenance; under capitalism the workers have to buy
their sustenance with their salary. Feudal exploitation requires
to one degree or another extra-economic coercion servitude while
for wage workers under capitalism, economic coercion is enough:
"if you don't work, you don't eat". Workers under capitalism are
free in a double sense, Marx tells us: "free" of means of production
with which to produce their own sustenance and free of any pressure
and requirement to work other than the simple necessity of earning
a living.10
Both Marx11 and Lenin12 point out that the most basic and simple
form of feudal exploitation consists of the peasant working part
of the time on the land of the landlord without payment to produce
a surplus. This basic configuration is found in the history of
Mexico in the specific form of the encomienda, the first colonial
form of exploitation of indigenous labour. Its owner, the encomiendero,
received from the Crown the right to the labour (as well as tribute
in the form of products) of the Indians of his encomienda, giving
them no compensation at all. Of course this feudal system of forced
labour was based on the most cruel coercion and violence against
the Indians and contributed to a great extent to the genocide
perpetuated against them.
The basic form of feudal exploitation was transformed and modified
in two main directions, without ever completely breaking out of
the framework of the feudal system. In terms of the exploitation
of the peasant parcel, the evolution of land rent (to which Marx
paid particular attention) passed from the basic form, already
described, of rent in labour, to rent in products (or sharecropping)13
and rent in money. Feudal rent, even in the case of money rent
which is often a transitional form, is the typical form of exploitation,
of the appropriation of the surplus, and as such it comprehends
all or almost all of the surplus. This is the distinction between
capitalist land rent, which is paid in money and which represents
only a fraction subtracted, and the typical form of capitalist
exploitation: profit realized through the exploitation of wage
labour.14
The feudal form of "personal prestation" ["prestation" refers
to the rendering of services due under feudal custom AWTW] by
the peasants (or "payment through labour") their unpaid labour
on the lands of the landlord also went through a process of development.15
Beginning with unpaid labour on the lands of the landlord as a
feudal obligation in exchange for the peasant's use of the parcel
in other words, the same basic form already described, considered
from its other aspect it developed into labour on the lands of
the landlord with some remuneration in products and to labour
partially remunerated with money. This feudal "personal prestation",
partially remunerated with money, is distinguished from capitalist
wage labour by the subsistence that the labourer derives from
his production on the parcel or receives in kind over and above
his wage in money, and by the existence of various forms of servitude,
of non-free forms of labour. Over and above these basic forms
of feudal exploitation land rent and personal prestation there
are numerous other specific forms of exploitation of the peasants
by the landlord class in any given feudal society.
In Mexico during the Colony there was a process of development
and transformation of feudal relations. There was the rise of
repartimiento which was distinguished from the encomienda in two
fundamental ways. First, the supply of indigenous labour was in
the hands of colonial authorities who parcelled the Indians out
among the particular landlords, in an attempt by the Crown to
prevent the creation in New Spain of independent fiefdoms that
could undermine its rule. Second, the Indians received (at least
in theory) a nominal payment in money, with the object being to
mitigate the purely coercive character of the labour system and
to slow the rapid extinction of the Indians (and therefore of
the source of exploited labour). Payment in money was purely nominal.
It did not compensate the labour of the Indians, whose sustenance
continued to come essentially from their own production (from
which they had to still pay tribute as well), nor did it eliminate
the need for coercion or the forced character of labour. For all
these reasons it must be considered a feudal form of exploitation.
Finally the hacienda [the large landed estate AWTW] made its appearance.
This would represent the typical form of feudal and semi-feudal
relations in Mexico until well into the twentieth century. The
two basic forms of production relations characteristic of the
haciendas were land rent (principally sharecropping) and personal
prestation in the form of peonage, although the feudal landlord
class also exploited the peasants in other forms, such as usury,
commercial retention of products, tribute, tithing, taxes, etc.,
which we will not analyze in detail here. (It should also be mentioned
that colonial society was not purely feudal because slavery also
existed.)
Under the regime of mediania, or sharecropping on hacienda lands,
the sharecropper had to deliver part of his harvest (generally
about half) to the hacienda, and in many cases the sharecropper
and/or his family members also had to work for a time without
pay on the hacienda. This form is clearly feudal in character
and was very important in the hacienda system, a fact which often
is omitted in attempts to characterize the hacienda as "capitalist".
Peonage assumed two forms: those called acasillados and the temporary
peons. The acasillados lived and worked permanently on the hacienda
and in exchange received a parcel of land (pejugal), a ration
of corn and other basic food and a wage. That is, it was personal
prestation compensated by the usufruct of the land, products and
money. As in the case of repartimiento, in spite of the wage,
it is a basically feudal form, in the first place because the
labourer continues to be tied to the land and the greater part
of his subsistence and compensation corresponds to his production
on the parcel and payment in kind. Even the supposed wage was
typically more of a form of internal accounting of payment in
kind by the hacienda, since most of the peon's small wage was
discounted to pay for provisions obtained in the hacienda "company
store".16 The acasillado also was not a free labourer, rather
typically he was tied to the hacienda through the mechanism of
debt when other terms of his treatment were insufficient to maintain
a permanent labour force.
The temporary peons who either lived near the hacienda or came
from outside and lived temporarily on the hacienda at times received
parcels of land or were paid a wage, often with a ration of corn.
The exploitation of the temporary peons was feudal in that their
sustenance came principally from their own production in their
village (supplemented with payment in kind when they did receive
it), and therefore the hacienda could pay a wage that did not
even cover their sustenance (which is, however, the "normal" case
in the capitalist system) and which for the most part they never
saw in the form of money but which disappeared into the accounts
of the hacienda's company store as payment of their debts.
Although the link of the temporary peons with the hacienda was
not as tight as that of the acasillados, theirs was not free labour
either. The Indians of the villages "naturally resisted being
temporarily rented out to the haciendas because this meant abandoning
their crops, yet without receiving any of the advantages of the
acasillados. When in these cases the promises and advance payments
didn't have the desired effect, the owners of the haciendas chose
to bribe the bosses of the villages to obtain the Indians they
needed, and as a final resort they used violence." "The system
of debts also was used to entice' or attract the Indians to the
hacienda. It was also very common to get Indians in by giving
them advances in the form of goods or wages for a day's work,
or paying debts they owed as tribute or obligations to the royal
hacienda or to the Church."17 All these forms are "tied", not
free labour forms; they are forms of servitude and therefore essentially
feudal.
These feudal production relations required an entire system of
extra-economic coercion which, besides the features already mentioned,
included the armed forces and private jails which the hacienda
owners used to impose their own laws. The system of coercion often
involved the Indian villages either through direct intervention,
or through the cacique bosses. Finally, the government authorities
and their armed forces reinforced the system where the power of
the hacienda owner alone was not enough, including through passing
legislation which recognised that the peons were attached to the
hacienda, spelling out that upon the sale of the hacienda the
peons would belong to the new buyer.18
The feudal production relations which defined the feudal character
of the society corresponded, as in feudal societies in general,
to relatively rudimentary forces of production and to a small-scale
agricultural and artisan economy. Even where agrarian exploitation
proceeded on a larger scale, for example, in the plantations,
it was extensive exploitation which achieved the larger scale
not through revolutionizing the forces of production but essentially
through repetition and aggregation on a single site of the productive
techniques characteristic of small-scale economy. Moreover, production
was carried out repeatedly on the same technical base, and technological
change was notably slow. This was in contrast to capitalism, where
"the bourgeoisie cannot exist except by incessantly revolutionizing
the instruments of production...".19 Although capital begins with
the forces of production inherited from feudalism, "only large
industry with its machinery provides a firm basis for capitalist
agriculture".20
Finally, the feudal character of the relations of production determined
that production for use21 would predominate in the economy, since
the peasants usually directly produced most of their own sustenance,
and a part of the surplus product either stayed on the hacienda
for use by the hacienda owner and his hangers on, or else went
to the direct use of the civilian and religious authorities through
tribute and in-kind tithing.
However, part of the surplus product typically was destined for
the market including the world market unlike the feudal societies
of Europe, Japan, China, etc, which existed before the rise of
capitalism and the world market. A part of the fruits of feudal
and colonial exploitation in New Spain passed through Spain, which
still was in a late stage of feudalism, to end up in the hands
of the capitalists of England, thus contributing to the so-called
"primitive accumulation" of capital. This fact has confused some
researchers like Frank, who claims that production in the Colony
was oriented to the market and that therefore "Iberoamerica (was)
capitalist not only in its cradle but even from conception".22
The basic methodological error of locating the essential difference
between feudalism and capitalism in the sphere of circulation
(production for use vs. production for the market) instead of
proceeding from the relations of production, as a Marxist does,
has been widely criticized, including by Marx himself.23 On the
other hand, as we have stated before, the greater part of the
production of the economy was indeed for use and although production
for use naturally tends to predominate under feudalism, a greater
or lesser part of the surplus typically is destined for the market,
and this was the case even in "classic" European feudalism.24
The link with the world market was certainly an important factor
which shaped the particular character of feudal and colonial society
in Mexico, but it does not contradict the essentially feudal character
of the relations of production and therefore of the society.
VII.
THE "GREEN REVOLUTION" AND BUREAUCRAT CAPITALISM IN AGRICULTURE
In the postwar period, the country experienced a rapid development
of bureaucrat capitalism (or bureaucrat-comprador, which is the
same thing), that is to say, capitalism in both the State sector
and "private enterprise" tied to imperialism and still linked
to semi-feudalism. Mexico became a semi-colonial and semi-feudal
country with significant growth in bureaucrat-comprador capitalism.
This process of transformation took two main roads: industrialization
through import substitution, sponsored by imperialist capital,
and the formation of a capitalist sector in agriculture. The agrarian
reform of the 1930s promoted the disintegration of the hacienda
as the dominant structure in the countryside and laid the basic
pattern for the subsequent transformation of land ownership. However,
the main direct impulse to the greater development of bureaucrat
capitalism in agriculture was the "green revolution". And the
green revolution was a project of U.S. imperialism.
The Office of Special Studies, which would lead the technical
innovations of the green revolution, was created in 1943, formally
as a semi-autonomous bureau of the Agriculture Secretariat, but
in reality a creature of the well-known Yankee imperialist political
instrument, the Rockefeller Foundation. The Foundation named the
head of the Office, provided the majority of the budget and hired
all of the scientific personnel. According to the Foundation report,
the initiative came from suggestions of the U.S. Ambassador to
Mexico, Josephus Daniels, who got Vice President Henry Wallace
to support it in the Roosevelt administration.25
The Office developed "improved seeds" and a whole package of inputs
irrigation, machinery, fertilizers, insecticides, etc. necessary
to achieve the predicted higher yields. Technological development
is not politically and socially "neutral". The programme was based
from the beginning on the presupposition of conditions typical
of big capitalist agriculture. The proposals of various Mexican
scientists to orient the programme to the conditions and needs
of peasant agriculture were rejected.26 In the 1950s and especially
beginning in the 1960s, the Rockefeller Foundation began to promote
this "green revolution" strategy, tested in Mexico, for other
countries in the Western bloc. The International Centre for Improvement
of Corn and Wheat, based in Mexico and financed mainly by the
Ford and Rockefeller Foundations, the Agency for International
Development, the World Bank, etc, has played a key role in this
effort.27
In Mexico the promotion of this technical package was accompanied
by a battery of government measures to foster large-scale capitalist
agriculture: large investments in irrigation, highways and aid
to marketing efforts, and other large subsidies granted to big
producers through guaranteed prices, credit policies, etc.28 These
initiatives were financed in great measure by imperialist capital
through loans from international banks and various "development"
institutions. At the same time direct foreign investment became
important in the formation of an agro-industrial complex which
provides inputs and processes the product of commercial agriculture.
As a result, the character of large-scale agriculture in the country
was significantly transformed. Consider the example of wheat,
a key crop in the first phases of the green revolution. In 1944
only Sonora cultivated wheat in more or less capitalist conditions,
reflected in a certain level of mechanization of harvesting. In
other regions of the country the primitive technique characteristic
of feudal agriculture a wooden plough pulled by oxen or mules
was the general rule.29
An important change got under way. From 1940 to 1960 the value
of agricultural machinery in the country multiplied almost eight
times in real pesos [Mexico's currency].30 In 1950 the national
consumption of nitrogen, phosphorus and potassium in fertilizers
still was only at the level of 11,700 tons, but by 1970 it reached
554,400 tons.31 Similar changes occurred in other areas of inputs
linked to modern agriculture.
These changes in the means of production correspond to the formation
of a large-scale agricultural sector in which the directly feudal
and semi-feudal relations characteristic of the old hacienda no
longer predominated and were replaced by relations of bureaucrat
capitalism which, nevertheless, continued to be closely tied to
semi-feudal relations in agriculture taken as a whole.
VIII.
BUREAUCRAT CAPITALISM AND SEMI-FEUDALISM
This new sector, which is predominantly capitalist in its internal
relations, is on the one hand extremely dependent on imperialist
capital and on the many aids and subsidies from the semi-colonial
State. On the other hand, it has subordinated, partially transformed
and integrated into its functioning the feudal relations in the
entire countryside. Feudal relations have been modified to a greater
or lesser degree as a result of its more direct subordination
to big capital. This is why we speak of semi-feudal relations
and semi-feudalism.
In the countryside, there are very few cases of purely capitalist
relations in which wages are the only source of maintenance for
the worker and his family and no form of extra-economic coercion
intervenes. The majority of those living in the countryside continue
to be linked to the peasant economy which suffers from semi-feudal
oppression. One part of big agriculture still is marked by important
semi-feudal features; and even that part of big agriculture which
is predominantly capitalist in its internal relations depends
on the wage complement which comes from the peasant economy and
semi-feudalism in the countryside in general as the essential
basis for the super-exploitation of the overwhelming majority
of its workers, the jornaleros. Therefore we can affirm that in
spite of the formation of a bigger or smaller capitalist sector
in its internal relations, the system of exploitation in the countryside
continues to be predominantly semi-feudal.
The core of today's semi-feudalism can be found in the persistence
of the latifundio system, the fact that the subordination of the
peasant economy continues to be the essential basis of the exploitation
carried out by the large agricultural holdings and, therefore,
serfdom is still in effect, and coercion is exercised against
the oppressed in the countryside, although in a modified manner.
The latifundio system persists in the system of land holding with
large and small landed estates, which is found in many countries
of Latin America and elsewhere, and in Mexico expresses itself
principally in the form of large holdings and communal holdings
(ejidos). In most cases the best lands the area covered by the
old hacienda and also new irrigated lands remain in the hands
of the landlords, either in the form of direct property, or through
renting of peasant lands, control of the latter by way of contracts,
open despoliation, etc.
What has changed is that production in these lands is according
to norms which are more or less capitalist we say "more or less"
because open semi-feudal forms, such as sharecropping, the system
of recruiting and indebtedness, unpaid labour, etc., are still
practised to some degree on part of these large land holdings,
and extensive production which has not yet reached the level of
typical capitalist dynamics persists above all in the large land
holdings dedicated to cattle raising. With the development of
capitalist production, the landlords have become more bourgeois
and more integrated with the bourgeoisie at the national level,
and some capitalists in other sectors have also entered into agricultural
production.
The essential basis of the system of exploitation is still the
domination and exploitation of the peasant economy, which takes
two forms: the system of peonage and the direct exploitation of
peasant production. The essential role of peasant production is
obvious in the case of the direct exploitation of the peasant
economy by means of sharecropping, usury, commerce, etc. In the
peonage system, although the form of exploiting jornaleros is
capitalist wage labour (often mixed with open semi-feudal forms,
with which we will deal later) the system presupposes that the
jornalero complements his wage with peasant production because
the wage is insufficient for his maintenance and reproduction.
In other words, the complement provided by the peasant economy
makes possible the absolute superexploitation of the jornalero,
payment below the minimum for the physical survival of the jornalero
and his family.
Therefore the overwhelming majority of the jornaleros are still
linked to the peasant economy. Either they own a small piece of
land, or they may have access to land through their relatives,
share tenancy, etc., or they may take part in activities linked
with the peasant economy, as artisans or small traders.32 The
minority of jornaleros who are not able to complement their wage
the so-called golondrinas (swallows) live a very precarious existence,
in that they find it almost impossible to have a family and children,
that is, to reproduce their labour power.
Thus there is an essentially semi-feudal root to both the system
of peonage as well as the direct exploitation of the peasant economy.
We have said that "pure" capitalism and capitalist wage labour
consist in the complete separation of the direct producers, the
workers, from the land or any other means by which they could
produce their subsistence. Consequently, all their compensation
is paid in the form of a money wage. In general, this is not yet
the case of the agricultural day labourers.
In contrast, feudalism is distinguished by the link between the
direct producers, the peasants, with the land, with which they
directly produce most of what is needed for their subsistence,
turning over the surplus to the landlord, either in the form of
labour ("personal prestation", "payment through work"), products
(sharecropping) or money rent. Or, as Lenin said, feudalism consists
in that "the land was divided between the big territorial landholders,
the feudal landlords, and that these assigned land to the peasants
to exploit them; therefore the land has been something like a
wage in kind; it provided the peasant with the necessities to
produce surplus product for the landlord; land constituted the
basis that made it possible for the peasants to deliver tributes
to the landlord".33
For this reason Lenin considered, for example, the parcels of
land the German landlords provided their salaried workers as "a
direct survival" of feudalism under capitalism, because "as an
economic system, serfdom differs from capitalism precisely in
that the former provides land to the labourer while the latter
separates the labourer from the land; the former gives the labourer
the means of subsistence in kind (or obliges him to produce this
on his parcel of land, whereas the latter pays the worker in money
with which he buys the means of subsistence".34
Moreover, the system of exploitation in the Mexican countryside
still assigns land (marginal lands in general) to the peasants
as an essential condition of their exploitation, either directly
or through peonage, and this fact constitutes the marrow of semi-feudalism
in the countryside. In its main form the State assigns them land,
as a landlord in fact, through the "ejido" system and in the interests
of the exploiting class as a whole. The survival of the latifundio
system under the regime of bureaucrat capitalism, which we have
already outlined, is accompanied by serfdom: unpaid labour; "tied",
not free, forms of labour; the personal dependence which sharecropping,
usury, etc., entail; the boss system, lack of freedom in general
in short, extra-economic coercion.
There are those who appreciate the enormous importance of the
dialectic between big agriculture and peasant economy but maintain
that this relation is completely capitalist because, in contrast
to the hacienda which contained the peasant's subsistence parcel,
that parcel is now outside, formally independent of the large
production entities.35 This point of view confounds the particular
form with the essential content of the relation. The system of
allotment (repartimiento) sent Indian peasants who lived and reproduced
in formally independent villages and lands to do forced labour,
and this did not cause it to cease to be a feudal labour system.
And the hacienda itself did not absorb the great majority of the
peasant parcels until the Porfiriato [dictatorial regime established
in Mexico by General Porfirio Diaz between 1876 and 1991 AWTW].
The system of exploitation of the feudal hacienda is based upon
the dialectic between the subsistence parcels inside or outside
the hacienda and the surplus work, the surplus product obtained
by the landholder through peonage and sharecropping on the lands
of the hacienda. After more than a century of transformation via
the landlord road, the dialectic between large holdings and small
peasant plots is still the essential basis of the system of exploitation.
To this essentially feudal foundation can be added various openly
semifeudal forms which are reinforced by this dialectic. Like
a string, on one end there appears the apparently capitalist advanced
large-scale agriculture and on the other a backward peasant agriculture
still wrapped in multiple forms of semi-feudal oppression. Between
them there exist various intermediate cases: big property that
still maintains openly semi-feudal features, peasant economy in
more prosperous areas which suffers more "modern" and capitalist
forms of exploitation.
They are not disconnected fragments or distinct economies. They
are two poles of a single system, of a necessary relationship.
From the peasant areas flow not only the labourers who work for
less than a pittance in the capitalist agriculture but also surplus
value sucked out of the peasant economy through usury, sharecropping,
etc. an intermediary mechanism that ultimately increases the profitability
of big capital. Thus the dialectic of exploitation is repeated:
between big and peasant agriculture, between irrigation and dry
land, between plain and mountain, between North and South the
dialectic of a bureaucrat capitalism which still cannot do without
semi-feudalism.
XV.
The Revolutionary Programme
The immediate alternative that stands out sharply in the class
struggle in the countryside is the peasant road. The main form
of the spontaneous struggle the struggle for land that moreover
arises from the most revolutionary strata in the countryside the
poor peasants aims at the destruction of large agricultural holdings
and the generalization of the peasant economy. All of the other
important forms of spontaneous struggle the struggle against the
political bosses (caciquismo), against repression, against the
imposition of corporativism, for higher prices and better working
conditions, for independent unions, etc. have an essentially democratic
character. The character of the struggle is not directly socialist
but rather democratic, a democratic struggle which attacks imperialism,
bureaucrat capitalism and semi-feudalism.
In the name of this struggle various reforms have been proposed
which supposedly favour the peasantry. Reforms alone will not
lead to liberation, even when they are instituted by the revolutionary
bourgeoisie. This is the lesson of three bourgeois revolutions
(Independence, the Reform and the Revolution) and more than 70
years of agrarian reforms. Today among the "socialists" (the great
majority of whom are not socialists at all but bourgeois forces,
in terms of their ideology and programme), two favourite proposals
are the promotion of collective ejidos and the amendment of the
Agrarian Reform law to limit so-called "small land holdings" to
20 hectares (50 acres) of irrigated land or its equivalent in
non-irrigated land.
It was correct to denounce the failed efforts at collectivization
under Echeveria as an attempt to set up, on peasant lands, capitalist
enterprises completely subordinate to and directed by the reactionary
state.36 The myth of the Cardenist collective ejidos has endured
longer, in part because the government decided afterwards to dismantle
the majority of them, not because they represented a "socialist
alternative" or some such trash, but because they were often bastions
of political forces which it sought to undermine (the Mexican
Communist Party, the PPS). Nevertheless, in the few collective
ejidos that have survived and been successful, we can see the
typical results of this reformism: the members, the ejidatarios,
no longer work their land but instead leave all the labour to
wage workers and live off the profits.37 Under capitalism, without
a genuine revolution, in the best of cases such "collectivization"
will be no more than that: relative privilege for a handful of
"partners" in a capitalist enterprise while the large majority
continue to live in misery.
Even more insidious is the proposal to amend the Agrarian Reform
law to limit agrarian property to 20 hectares of irrigated land,
because in appearance it incorporates the peasants' demand for
land, but it does so in a form which will only assure continued
oppression. Over the last 70 years it has not even occurred to
these gentlemen, these respectable "socialists", that the Agrarian
Reform law is a reactionary instrument of the bureaucrat bourgeoisie.
What an ultra-leftist idea! It would be better to reform the Reform
so that the worshippers of bourgeois legalism can fall for it
another 70 years.... Lenin was fully justified in saying that
the opportunists are better defenders of the bourgeoisie than
the bourgeoisie itself.
Why is it that 70 years after the Agrarian Reform the peasants
are worse off than ever? Why is it that many of the political
bosses of later years in the beginning were "leaders" of that
reform who emerged from the Agrarian Reform struggle of the 1930s?
Why did that reform establish the basis for the complete subjugation
of the peasantry to the bureaucrat bourgeoisie? It was not because
the limit of the "small" holdings was 100 hectares instead of
20. It was because the law and the Constitution guaranteed and
continue to guarantee that the turning over of the land would
depend upon the decision of the bourgeois state, in a completely
conscious effort by the bourgeoisie to subdue and control the
revolutionary struggle of the peasants which the authors of the
1917 Constitution drowned in blood at the same time as they were
writing their precious document. That type of agrarian reform
that depends upon the "good will" of the bourgeois state, even
if it had a formal limit of 20 acres (or 10 or 5), will always
be gotten around in part; but even more important, even if it
were applied to the letter of the law, the turning over of the
land will always come at the price of the subordination and domination
of the peasants by the reactionary state. And therefore the domination
of big capital and imperialism will remain intact.
The only road to liberation is revolution, and a revolution, as
Engels had occasion to remind the reformist socialist of his day,
is an act of violence by which one class overthrows another. The
road to liberation is People's War which smashes the bourgeois
state instead of trying to reform it. That is the first requirement.
That revolution must be a New Democratic revolution led by the
proletariat and its Marxist-Leninist-Maoist party to overthrow
imperialism, big capitalism and semi-feudalism, establish the
people's democratic dictatorship of the revolutionary classes
and launch the socialist revolution. This is the second requirement.
(Is it necessary to add that the new revolutionary state will
not base itself on the bourgeois Constitution of 1917?) Outside
the general framework of these two requirements, the true liberation
of the oppressed, whether in the countryside or the cities, is
an impossible illusion.
In this context, the agrarian revolution must be carried out in
two phases. The peasants themselves, arms in hand, will seize
without compensation the lands of the big capitalists and the
big landlords (in accordance with the concrete conditions it could
be correct to offer some form of compensation to intermediate
forces) and redistribute all of the land. Of course this process
must be guided by general criteria formulated by the party and
the new revolutionary state, but it must be the work of the revolutionary
peasants themselves, since simply handing over the land as a "gift"
from the state, even if that state is thoroughly revolutionary,
cannot unleash the conscious revolutionary initiative of the masses,
which is the only thing that can guarantee the victory of the
socialist cause. In this redistribution, the historic rights of
Indian groups to the land must be respected as part of the overall
struggle to eliminate the oppression of these national minorities.
Imperialist capital and its enterprises as well as those of the
comprador bourgeoisie must be confiscated. Their enterprises that
provide inputs to the agricultural sector or that market and process
its products must become the property of the nation. A struggle
will have to be waged to transform the character of former private
and state-owned enterprises so that they may serve the agrarian
revolution and the peasants, the socialist transformation of the
country, and the world proletarian revolution. In terms of enterprises
that are specifically agricultural, in general the machinery and
some other means of production should not simply be turned over
to the peasants who happen to receive the land where these are
located, since this would reproduce the current irrational and
unequal concentration. Mechanisms must be established for their
equal distribution and their collective use.
The first phase of the agrarian revolution will do away completely
with semi-feudalism and will smash imperialism and bureaucrat-comprador
capital. It will create an opening for a nascent socialist economic
sector and a new free peasant economy and will represent a great
step forward. However, in the end, the "free" (spontaneous) development
of the peasant economy according to the laws of the market is
a form of capitalist development which leads to polarization of
the peasantry into a minority of capitalists and a great majority
of exploited. Only socialism can liberate the peasants. Collectivization,
a useless reform under capitalism, in the context of the political
power of the proletariat and the other revolutionary classes and
the initiation of the socialist revolution throughout society,
becomes the road to socialism in the countryside.
Why if bureaucrat capitalism in many cases has already socialised
to a significant degree the process of agricultural production
do we call for dividing up the land only to later call for socializing
production through collectivization? Why not convert the large
agricultural holdings directly into state or collective property?
There are some means of production like high-tech cow milk production
that should be made use of, and in which some form of social property
will be necessary from the beginning; and as already stated, agricultural
machinery in general will have to be employed in some form that
allows for a more equitable distribution and collective use. However,
the division of the land among the peasants is in a general sense
a necessary step for three reasons:
First, it corresponds to the most thorough elimination of semi-feudal
relations and the subordination of the peasant economy, and will
lead (along with more equal distribution of machinery, credit
and other inputs) to minimizing today's large disequilibriums,
distortions and inequalities in agriculture. In contrast, the
direct conversion of the large agricultural enterprises into state
property or collective enterprises, which would inevitably involve
only a minority of peasants, would leave intact the concentrations
of the means of production in a limited sector and maintain the
backwardness of the overall peasant economy.
Second, true revolutionary transformation requires the most profound
rupture with imperialism: self-sufficiency, abolition of technological
dependency on the supply of machinery and other inputs, the reorientation
of production for the imperialist markets toward production for
the needs of the masses, etc. All of this (and the revolutionary
war itself) implies certain disruptions in highly technological
forms of production. The peasants, in contrast, have a great wealth
of experience in production with limited technology. On the other
hand, the peasant economy adapts naturally to the production of
basic foodstuffs, and agriculture will have to be reoriented urgently
toward that sort of production. In contrast, the policy of directly
converting the large holdings into state property in situations
in which agriculture is still not capitalist has been part of
the programme which leaves intact essential elements of the dependency
on imperialism (of both blocs) for technology, machinery, credits,
and markets. This has been the experience of the Cuban and Nicaraguan
revolutions which did not overcome the structure of agricultural/export
dependency.
Finally, the most important reason is political: the main struggle
of the oppressed in the countryside today is the struggle for
land, and that struggle must be respected. The redivision of the
land by the revolutionary peasants will strengthen the worker-peasant
alliance under proletarian leadership as the core of the new state
power and will create the firmest possible basis for collectivization
to be truly voluntary and a conscious act of the peasants themselves.
The successful struggle in China, which culminated with the formation
of the communes, showed that when collectivization is the product
of the conscious revolutionary struggle of the peasants under
the leadership of the communist party, the process gives a great
boost to the enthusiasm and initiative of the masses in the socialist
revolution. In contrast, the errors committed in the first historic
experience of collectivization in the Soviet Union illustrate
that even when collectivization is carried forward by a genuinely
socialist government (as was the Soviet government at that time),
if it cannot count on the full support and participation of the
poor and lower middle peasants in the struggle against very real
enemies who wish to consolidate capitalist relations, it can undermine
the initiative of the masses and end up weakening the very base
of the socialist government itself.
Thus we must make sure that the peasants' struggle for land reaches
its ultimate revolutionary objective and that the peasants demonstrate,
with their own experience, that only socialism, only the road
of collectivization, can liberate them. In the course of the struggle
we must support every spark of cooperation, and it is possible
that in some cases, upon redistributing the land, the peasants
will choose to immediately organize collective forms of production.
At all times the impulse toward such transformations must come
from the communist party's political leadership of the conscious
revolutionary struggle of the peasants, and not from bureaucratic
methods.
In reality, the line of going "directly to socialism" in the countryside,
which is pushed by the various revisionist forces who are in the
habit of negating the existence of semi-feudal relations, is simply
a line which would speed up the development of bureaucrat capitalism.
It is possible to overcome semi-feudal relations either by the
peasant road or the landlord road. In negating the continued existence
of semi-feudal relations, they are rejecting the revolutionary
road the road of the peasants and opting for an acceleration of
the reactionary landlord road. This idea goes no further than
converting the large holdings into state property, which leaves
intact both its dependence on imperialism and the inequalities
and disarticulation inherent in the relationship between large
and small holdings. The general programme of these forces is not
socialist nor even democratic. It does not seek a radical rupture
with the world system, but at most to develop closer ties with
Soviet social-imperialism and negotiate a "better arrangement"
with Yankee imperialism.
For all these reasons, the distribution of the land is a necessary
culmination of the democratic revolution in the countryside. The
subsequent collectivization will represent an immense and historic
socialist transformation of the Mexican countryside. However,
the struggle will not stop there. As we have been taught by Mao
and by the experience of both the Chinese revolution and the restoration
of capitalism there and in the Soviet Union, it will be necessary
to continue the revolution within socialism. It will be necessary
to combat the new bourgeois elements that inevitably emerge inside
the socialist forms of property and inside the communist party
itself. It will be necessary to struggle to overcome the many
inequalities that still remain and which provide a basis for such
bourgeois forces. Only the triumph of communism, of classless
society, throughout the world will represent the final victory.
Even so, the great revolution whose agrarian component we have
outlined here will be a great advance, not only for the people
of Mexico, but also for the oppressed throughout the world in
their struggle for this promising future.
In the countryside, as throughout the country, the old order is
in a deep crisis. Let the government shed crocodile tears for
the "poor peasants". Let the reformists promise this or that reform
if only we vote for them or sign up for one of their organizations.
This is the role they are supposed to be playing. The role of
revolutionaries, in contrast, is to arouse the "invisible" people
the proletarians and the peasants arouse them not only to cry
out loud and bitter denunciations which they now only murmur,
not only to rise up with swords and bullets against injustice,
but also so that the invisible people can come out from their
shadows this time for good and smash and uproot the evil forces
which have bled them dry in the darkness, and with great revolutionary
strides begin to build a new and shining society in their own
image.
footnotes
1. See Lenin,
V.I., The Agrarian Programme and Social Democracy in the First
Russian Revolution (1905-1907), sections 5 and 6 of Chapter 1.
2. Mao Tsetung,
"The Current Situation and Our Tasks", Selected Works, Vol. 4.
3. Bartra,
Armando, Los harederos de Zapata, Era, 1985; Paré, Luisa, El proletariado
agrícola en México, Siglo XXI, Mexico, 1982, p. 40.
4. Bartra,
Roger, "Campesinado y poder político en México", in Roger Bartra,
et al., Caciquismo y poder político en el México rural, Siglo
XXI, Mexico, 1975, p. 18.
5. See, for
example, Lenin, V.I., Two Tactics of Social Democracy in the Russian
Revolution.
6. 48% of
the population lives in concentrations of less than 15,000 inhabitants
according to the figures of the X Censo de poblacion y vivienda
1980 reproduced in Banamex, México social 1985-1986, p. 64. The
official figures tend to underestimate the rural population.
7. According
to a report drawn up by professors at the Universidad de Chapingo
and the PMS parliamentary group for the period January 1982-July
1987, La Jornada, 19 and 31 August 1987.
8. Mao Tsetung,
"Report on an Investigation into the Hunan Peasant Movement",
Selected Works, Vol. 1.
9. Mao Tsetung,
"On the Problem of agricultural collectivization", Selected Works,
Vol. 5.
10. Marx,
Karl, Capital, Vol. I, Chapter XXIV.
11. Ibid.,
Vol. III, Chapter XLVII, part 2.
12. Lenin,
V.I., The Development of Capitalism in Russia, particularly Chapter
III.
13. Marx
makes a distinction between "rent in products", in which the peasant
works the land with his own animals and implements (which is a
purely feudal form, because all the surplus corresponds to land
rent), and "sharecropping", in which the landlord, besides, the
land, also supplies draft animals, implements, etc. In this last
case, rent includes, besides land rent, a recompense for the instruments
of production provided in advance by the landlord, and Marx considers
it a transitional form toward capitalism, and thus itself semifeudal.
In Mexico, the term "sharecropping" has typically been used to
refer to both forms, and for reasons of simplicity we will continue
this usage here. On the other hand, the greater proliferation
of the sharecropping form (in the strict sense used by Marx) relative
to rent in products during the second half of the 19th century
did reflect the beginning of the transition to capitalism. However,
the existence of sharecropping in the strict sense in a far earlier
period was due principally to the fact that it was the Spaniards
who introduced draft animals here. This particularity of the development
of feudalism in Mexico also determined that the use by the peasants
of their own draft animals in their "personal prestation", that
is, in their unpaid labour on the lands of the landlord, never
achieved much importance in New Spain [the Spanish viceroyship
in America which coincides with contemporary Mexico AWTW].
14. Marx,
Capital, Vol. III, Chapter XLVII.
15. Lenin
analyzed this in the Russian case: see The Development of Capitalism
in Russia, Chapter III.
16. Esteva,
Gustavo, La batalla en el México rural, Siglo XXI, Mexico, 1985,
p. 135; Espin, Jaime y Patricia de Leonardo, Economía y sociedad
en Los Altos de Jalisco, Nueva Imagen, Mexico, 1978, p. 65.
17. Florescano,
Enrique, Origen y desarrollo de los problemas agrarios de México
1500-182, Era, Mexico, 1976, pages 106, 107.
18. Ibid.,
pages 107-108.
19. Karl
Marx and Fredrick Engels, Manifesto of the Communist Party.
20. Marx,
Capital, Vol. I.
21. Solis,
Leopoldo, La realidad economica mexicana, Mexico, Siglo XXI, 1983,
p. 17.
22. Gunder
Frank, André, et al., America Latina, feudalismo o capitalismo,
Ed. Quinto Sol, Mexico, p. 64.
23. See the
Dobb - Sweezy critique in Hilton, Rodney, La transicion del feudalismo
al capitalismo, Ed. Grijalbo, Barcelona, 1977, as well as the
comments by Marx in Capital, Vol. III, Chapter XX.
24. Hilton,
op. cit., pages 20, 156, etc.
25. Esteva,
op. cit., pages 62-63; Hewitt de Alcántara, Cynthia, La modernización
de la agricultura mexicana 1940-1970, Siglo XXI, Mexico, 1982,
pages 32-33.
26. Hewitt
de A., op.cit., pages 46-49 and in general Chapter 1, "Las implicaciones
sociales de la investigación agrícola en México".
27. Ibid.,
pages 53-55.
28. Ibid.,
Chapter 2, "El marco institutional para el crecimiento agrícola".
29. Ibid.,
p. 37.
30. Ibid.,
p. 76.
31. Ibid.,
p. 83.
32. Esteva,
op.cit. p. 156-158; Astorga Lira, Enrique, Mercado de trabajo
rural en México, La mercancia humana, Era, Mexico, 1985, pages
51, 111; Paré, Luisa, El proletariado agricola en México, Siglo
XXI, Mexico, 1982, p. 8.
33. Lenin,
V.I. Who Are the "Friends of the People" and How They Fight the
Social-Democrats, Vol. 1.
34. Lenin,
V.I., "The Capitalist System of Modern Agriculture, Collected
Works, Vol. 16.
35. De Janvy,
Alain, The Agrarian Question, John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore,
1981, p. 209.
36, Warman,
Arturo, "La colectivizacion en el campo: una critica", Ensayos
sobre el campesinado en México, Nueva Imagen, Mexico, 1984.
37. Hewitt
de Alcantara, op.cit., pages 195-214.